% SiSU 0.38 @title: Book Index for - The Wealth of Networks @subtitle: How Social Production Transforms Markets and Freedom @creator: Yochai Benkler @type: Book @rights: Copyright 2006 by Yochai Benkler. All rights reserved. Subject to the exception immediately following, this book may not be reproduced, in whole or in part, including illustrations, in any form (beyond that copying permitted by Sections 107 and 108 of the U.S. Copyright Law and except by reviewers for the public press), without written permission from the publishers. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/2.5/ The author has made an online version of the book available under a Creative Commons Noncommercial Sharealike license; it can be accessed through the author's website at http://www.benkler.org. @date: 2006-01-27 @date.created: 2006-01-27 @date.issued: 2006-01-27 @date.available: 2006-11-26 @date.modified: 2006-11-26 @date.valid: 2006-01-27 % @catalogue: isbn=0300110561 @language: US @vocabulary: none @images: center @skin: skin_won_benkler @links: {The Wealth of Networks, dedicated wiki}http://www.benkler.org/wealth_of_networks/index.php/Main_Page {The Wealth of Networks, Yochai Benkler @ SiSU}http://www.jus.uio.no/sisu/the_wealth_of_networks.yochai_benkler @level: new=:C; break=1 :A~ The Wealth of Networks - How Social Production Transforms Markets and Freedom :B~ Yochai Benkler :C~ Book Index 1~ Index~{ http://www.jus.uio.no/sisu/the_wealth_of_networks.yochai_benkler }~ http://www.jus.uio.no/sisu/the_wealth_of_networks.yochai_benkler ~# Abilene, Texas, 407 access: broadband services, concentration of, 240; cable providers, regulation of, 399-401; human development and justice, 13-15; influence exaction, 156, 158-159; large-audience programming, 197, 204-210, 259-260; limited by mass media, 197-199; to medicine, 344-353; to raw data, 313-314; systematically blocked by policy routers, 147-149, 156, 197-198, 397 access regulation. See policy accreditation, 68, 75-80, 169-174, 183-184; Amazon, 75; capacity for, by mass media, 199; concentration of mass-media power, 157, 220-225, 235, 237-241; as distributed system, 171-172; Google, 76; Open Directory Project (ODP), 76; power of mass media owners, 197, 199-204, 220-225; as public good, 12; Slashdot, 76-80, 104 Ackerman, Bruce, 184, 281, 305-307 action, individual. See individual capabilities active vs. passive consumers, 126-127, 135 ad hoc mesh networks, 89 Adamic, Lada, 244, 246-248, 257 Adams, Scott, 138 advertiser-supported media, 194-195, 199-204; lowest-common-denominator programming, 197, 204-210, 259-260; reflection of consumer preference, 203 aggregate effect of individual action, 4-5. See also clusters in network topology; peer production agonistic giving, 83 agricultural innovation, commons-based, 329-344 % ,{[pg 492]}, Albert, Reka, 243-244, 251 alertness, undermined by commercialism, 197, 204-210 alienation, 359-361 allocating excess capacity, 81-89, 114-115, 157, 351-352 almanac-type information, emergence of, 70. See also Wikipedia project Alstott, Anne, 305 altruism, 82-83 Amazon, 75 anticircumvention provisions, DMCA, 414-417 antidevice provisions, DMCA, 415 Antidilution Act of 1995, 290, 447 appropriation strategies, 49 arbitrage, domain names, 433 archiving of scientific publications, 325-326 Arrow, Kenneth, 36, 93 ArXiv.org, 325-326 asymmetric commons, 61-62 AT&T, 191, 194 Atrios (blogger Duncan Black), 263 attention fragmentation, 15, 234-235, 238, 256, 465-466. See also social relations and norms authoring of scientific publications, 323-325 authoritarian control, 236; working around, 266-271 authorship, collaborative. See peer production autonomy, 8-9, 133-175, 464-465; culture and, 280-281; formal conception of, 140-141; independence of Web sites, 103; individual capabilities in, 20-22; information environment, structure of, 146-161; mass media and, 164-166 B92 radio, 266 Babel objection, 10, 12, 169-174, 233-235, 237-241, 465-466 backbone Web sites, 249-250, 258-260 background knowledge. See culture bad luck, justice and, 303-304 Bagdikian, Ben, 205 Baker, Edwin, 165, 203 Balkin, Jack, 15, 256, 276, 284, 294, 295 Barabasi, Albert-Laszlo, 243-246, 251 Barbie (doll), culture of, 277, 285-289 Barlow, John Perry, 45 barriers to access. See access BBC (British Broadcasting Corporation), 189 Beebe, Jack, 207 behavior: enforced with social software, 372-375; motivation to produce, 6, 92-99, 115; number and variety of options, 150-152, 170. See also autonomy Benabou, Roland, 94 benefit maximization, 42 Beniger, James, 187 Benjamin, Walter, 295, 296 Bennett, James Gordon, 188 Berlusconi effect, 201, 204, 220-225 bilateral trade negotiations. See trade policy BioForge platform, 343 bioinformatics, 351 BioMed Central, 324 biomedical research, commons-based, 344-353 BIOS initiative, 342-344 biotechnology, 332-338 blocked access: authoritarian control, 236, 266-271; autonomy and, 147-152, 170-171; influence exaction, 156, 158-159; large-audience programming, 197, 204-210, 259-260; mass media and, 197-199; policy routers, 147-149, 156, 197-198, 397 blogs, 216-217; Sinclair Broadcasting case study, 220-225; small-worlds effect, 252-253; as social software, 372-375; watchdog functionality, 262-264 % ,{[pg 493]}, blood donation, 93 bots. See trespass to chattels bow tie structure of Web, 249-250 Bower, Chris, 221 boycott of Sinclair Broadcasting, 220-225 BoycottSBG.com site, 222-223, 225 Boyd, Dana, 368 Boyle, James, 25, 415, 446-447, 449, 487-488 branding: domain names and, 431-433; trademark dilution, 290, 446-448 bridging social relationships, 368 Bristol, Virginia, 406 broadband networks, 24-25; cable as commons, 399-401; concentration in access services, 240; market structure of, 152-153; municipal initiatives, 405-408; open wireless networks, 402-405; regulation of, 399-402. See also wired communications broadcast flag regulation, 410 broadcasting, radio. See radio broadcasting, toll, 194-195 Broder, Andrei, 249 browsers, 434-436 Bt cotton, 337-338 building on existing information, 37-39, 52 Bullock, William, 188 business decisions vs. editorial decisions, 204 business strategies for information production, 41-48 cable broadband transport, as commons, 399-401. See also broadband networks cacophony. See Babel objection; relevance filtering CAMBIA research institute, 342-344 capabilities of individuals, 20-22; coordinated effects of individual actions, 4-5; cultural shift, 284; economic condition and, 304; human capacity as resource, 52-55; as modality of production, 119-120; as physical capital, 99; technology and human affairs, 16-18. See also autonomy; nonmarket information producers capacity: diversity of content in largeaudience media, 197, 204-210, 259-260; human communication, 52-55, 99-106, 110; mass media limits on, 199; networked public sphere generation, 225-232; networked public sphere reaction, 220-225; opportunities created by social production, 123-126; policy routers, 147-149, 156, 197-198, 397; processing (computational), 81-82, 86; radio, sharing, 402-403; securing, 458; sharing, 81-89, 114-115, 157, 351-352; storage, 86; transaction costs, 112-115 capital for production, 6-7, 32; control of, 99; cost minimization and benefit maximization, 42; fixed and initial costs, 110; production costs as limiting, 164-165; transaction costs, 59-60. See also commons; social capital Carey, James, 131 carriage requirements of cable providers, 401 Castells, Manuel, 16, 18, 362 CBDPTA (Consumer Broadband and Digital Television Promotion Act), 409 Cejas, Rory, 134, 141-142 censorship, 268-270 centralization of communications, 62, 235, 237-241, 258-260; authoritarian filtering, 268; decentralization, 10-12, 62 CGIAR's GCP program, 341 Chakrabarti, Soumen, 251 Chandler, Alfred, 187 channels, transmission. See transport channel policy chaotic, Internet as, 237-241 % ,{[pg 494]}, Chaplin, Charlie, 138 chat rooms, 269 Chinese agricultural research, 337-338 Chung, Minn, 267 Cisco policy routers, 147-149, 156, 197-198, 397; influence exaction, 156, 158-159 Clark, Dave, 412 Clarke, Ian, 269 click-wrap licenses, 444-446 clickworkers project (NASA), 69-70 clinical trials, peer-produced, 353 clusters in network topology, 12-13, 248-250, 253-256; bow tie structure of Web, 249-250; synthesis of public opinion, 184, 199. See also topology, network Coase, Ronald, 59, 87 Cohen, Julie, 416 Coleman, James, 95, 361 collaboration, open-source, 66-67 collaboration, traditional. See traditional model of communication collaborative authorship, 218; among universities, 338-341, 347-350; social software, 372-375. See also peer production collective social action, 22 commercial culture, production of, 295-296 commercial mass media: basic critiques of, 196-211; corrective effects of network environment, 220-225; as platform for public sphere, 178-180, 185-186, 198-199; structure of, 178-180. See also traditional model of communication commercial mass media, political freedom and, 176-211; criticisms, 196-211; design characteristics of liberal public sphere, 180-185 commercial model of communication, 4, 9, 22-28, 59-60, 383-459, 470-471; autonomy and, 164-166; barriers to justice, 302; emerging role of mass media, 178-180, 185-186, 198-199; enclosure movement, 380-382; mapping, framework for, 389-396; medical innovation and, 345-346; path dependency, 386-389; relationship with social producers, 122-127; security-related policy, 73-74, 396, 457-459; shift away from, 10-13; stakes of information policy, 460-473; structure of mass media, 178-180; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116. See also market-based information producers commercial press, 186-188, 202 commercialism, undermining political concern, 197, 204-210 common-carriage regulatory system, 160 commons, 24, 60-62, 129-132, 316-317; autonomy and, 144-146; cable providers as, 399-401; crispness of social exchange, 109; human welfare and development, 308-311; municipal broadband initiatives, 405-408; types of, 61-62; wireless communications as, 89, 152-154 commons, production through. See peer production commons-based research, 317-328, 354-355; food and agricultural innovation, 328-344; medical and pharmaceutical innovation, 344-353 communication: authoritarian control, working around, 266-271; capacity of, 52-55; feasibility conditions for social production, 99-106; pricing, 110; thickening of preexisting relations, 357; through performance, 205; transaction costs, 112-115; university alliances, 338-341, 347-350. See also wired communications; wireless communications % ,{[pg 495]}, communication diversity. See diversity communication tools, 215-219 communities: critical culture and self-reflection, 15-16, 70-74, 76, 112, 293-294; fragmentation of, 15, 234-235, 238, 256, 465-466; human and Internet, together, 375-377; immersive entertainment, 74, 135-136; municipal broadband initiatives, 405-408; open wireless networks, 402-405; as persons, 19-20; technology-defined social structure, 29-34; virtual, 348-361 community clusters. See clusters in network topology community regulation by social norms. See social relations and norms competition: communications infrastructure, 157-159; market and nonmarket producers, 122-123 computational capacity, 81-82, 86; transaction costs, 112-115 computer gaming environment, 74, 135-136 computers, 105; infrastructure ownership, 155; policy on physical devices, 408-412; as shareable, lumpy goods, 113-115 concentration in broadband access services, 240 concentration of mass-media power, 157, 197, 199-204, 235, 237-241; corrective effects of network environment, 220-225 concentration of Web attention, 241-261 connectivity, 86 constraints of information production, monetary, 6-7, 32; control of, 99; cost minimization and benefit maximization, 42; fixed and initial costs, 110; production costs as limiting, 164-165; transaction costs, 59-60. See also commons; social capital constraints of information production, physical, 3-4, 24-25. See also capital for production constraints on behavior. See autonomy; freedom consumer demand for information, 203 consumer surplus. See capacity, sharing consumerism, active vs. passive, 126-127, 135 contact, online vs. physical, 360-361 content layer of institutional ecology, 384, 392, 439-457, 469-470; copyright issues, 439-444; recent changes, 395 context, cultural. See culture contractual enclosure, 444-446 control of public sphere. See mass media controlling culture, 297-300 controversy, avoidance of, 205 cooperation gain, 88 cooperative production. See peer production coordinated effects of individual actions, 4-5. See also clusters in network topology; peer production copyleft, 65, 342 copyright issues, 277-278, 439-444. See also proprietary rights core Web sites, 249-250 cost: crispness of, 109-113; minimizing, 42; of production, as limiting, 164-165; proprietary models, 461-462; technologies, 462. See also capital for production creative capacity, 52-55; feasibility conditions for social production, 99-106; pricing, 110 Creative Commons initiative, 455 creativity, value of, 109-113 credibility, earning. See accreditation criminalization of copyright infringement, 441-442 crispness of currency exchange, 109-113 % ,{[pg 496]}, critical culture and self-reflection, 15-16, 293-294; Open Directory Project, 76; self-identification as transaction cost, 112; Wikipedia project, 70-74 cultural production. See culture; information production culture, 273-300, 466-467; criticality of (self-reflection), 15-16, 70-74, 76, 112, 293-294; freedom of, 279-285, 297; influence exaction, 156, 158-159; as motivational context, 97; participatory, policies for, 297-300; security of context, 143-146; shaping perceptions of others, 147-152, 170, 220-225, 297-300; social exchange, crispness of, 109-113; of television, 135; transparency of, 285-294 daily newspapers, 40 dailyKos.com site, 221 data storage capacity, 86; transaction costs, 112-115 Database Directive, 449-450 database protection, 449-451; trespass to chattels, 451-453 Davis, Nick, 221-223, 245-246, 260 Dawkins, Richard, 284 de minimis digital sampling, 443-444 de Solla Price, Derek, 243 Dean, Howard, 258 decency. See social relations and norms decentralization of communications, 10-12, 62 Deci, Edward, 94 DeCSS program, 417 defining price, 109-113 demand for information, consumer, 203 demand-side effects of information production, 43, 45 democratic societies, 7-16, 177; autonomy, 8-9; critical culture and social relations, 15-16; independence of Web sites, 103; individual capabilities in, 20-22; justice and human development, 13-15; public sphere, shift from mass media, 10-13; shift from mass-media communications model, 10-13; social-democratic theories of justice, 308-311 democratizing effect of Internet, 213-214; critiques of claims of, 233-237 depression, 359-361 deregulation. See policy determinism, technological, 16-18 development, commons-based, 317-328, 354-355; food and agricultural innovation, 328-344; medical and pharmaceutical innovation, 344-353 devices (physical), policy regarding, 408-412. See also computers Diebold Election Systems, 225-232, 262, 389-390 digital copyright. See proprietary rights digital divide, 236-237 Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA), 380, 413-418 digital sampling, 443-444 dignity, 19 Dill, Stephen, 249-250 dilution of trademarks, 290, 446-448 discussion lists (electronic), 215 displacement of real-world interaction, 357, 362-366 distributed computing projects, 81-83 distributed filtering and accreditation, 171-172 distributed production. See peer production Distributed Proofreading site, 81 distribution lists (electronic), 215 distribution of information, 68-69, 80-81; power law distribution of site connections, 241-261; university-based innovation, 348-350 diversity, 164-169; appropriation strategies, 49; of behavioral options, 150-152, 170; changes in taste, 126; fragmentation of communication, 15, 234-235, 238, 256, 465-466; granularity of participation, 100-102, 113-114; human communication, 55-56; human motivation, 6; large-audience programming, 197, 204-210, 259-260; mass-mediated environments, 165-166; motivation to produce, 6, 92-99, 115. See also autonomy % ,{[pg 497]}, DMCA (Digital Millennium Copyright Act), 380, 413-418 Doctors Without Borders, 347 domain name system, 429-434 Drezner, Daniel, 251, 255 drugs, commons-based research on, 344-353 DSL. See broadband networks dumb luck, justice and, 303-304 Dworkin, Gerard, 140 Dworkin, Ronald, 304, 307 dynamic inefficiency. See efficiency of information regulation Dyson, Esther, 45 e-mail, 215; thickening of preexisting relations, 363-366 /{eBay v. Bidder's Edge}/, 451-453 economic analysis, role of, 18 economic data, access to, 313-314 economic opportunity, 130-131 economics in liberal political theory, 19-20; cultural freedom, 279-285, 297 economics of information production and innovation, 35-58; current production strategies, 41-48; exclusive rights, 49-50, 56-58; production over computer networks, 50-56 economics of nonmarket production, 91-127; emergence in digital networks, 116-122; feasibility conditions, 99-106; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116. See also motivation to produce Edelman, Ben, 268 editorial filtering. See relevance filtering editorial vs. business decisions, 204 educational instruction, 314-315, 327 efficiency of information regulation, 36-41, 49-50, 106-116, 461-462; capacity reallocation, 114-116; property protections, 319; wireless communications policy, 154 Eisenstein, Elizabeth, 17 /{Eldred v. Ashcroft}/, 442 electronic voting machines (case study), 225-232, 262, 389-390 emergent order in networks. See clusters in network topology enclosure movement, 380-382 encryption, 457 encryption circumvention, 414-417 encyclopedic information, emergence of, 70. See also Wikipedia project enhanced autonomy. See autonomy entertainment industry: hardware regulation and, 409-412; immersive, 74, 135-136; peer-to-peer networks and, 425-428. See also music industry entitlement theory, 304 environmental criticism of GM foods, 334 equality. See justice and human development esteem. See intrinsic motivations ethic (journalistic) vs. business necessity, 197, 204-210 excess capacity, sharing, 81-89, 114-115, 157, 351-352 exclusivity. See also proprietary rights exercise of programming power, 197, 199-204; corrective effects of network environment, 220-225 existing information, building on, 37-39, 52 extrinsic motivations, 94-95 factual reporting, access to, 314 fair use in copyright, 440-441 family relations, strengthening of, 357, 362-366 % ,{[pg 498]}, Fanning, Shawn, 84, 419 Farrell, Henry, 251, 255 FastTrack architecture, 420 FCC. See policy feasibility conditions for social production, 99-106 feedback and intake limits of mass media, 199 Feinberg, Joel, 140 /{Feist Publications, Inc. v. Rural Tel. Serv. Co.}/, 449 Felten, Edward, 416 FHSST (Free High School Science Texts), 101, 326 Fightaids@home project, 82 file-sharing networks, 83-86, 418-428; security considerations, 457 filtering, 68, 75-80, 169-174, 183, 258-260; Amazon, 75; by authoritarian countries, 236; capacity for, by mass media, 199; concentration of massmedia power, 157, 197, 199-204, 235, 237-241; corrective effects of network environment, 220-225; as distributed system, 171-172; Google, 76; Open Directory Project (ODP), 76; as public good, 12; Slashdot, 76-80, 104; watchdog functionality, 236, 261-266 filtering by information provider. See blocked access financial reward, as demotivator, 94-96 fine-grained goods, 113 firms. See market-based information producers; traditional model of communication first-best preferences, mass media and: concentration of mass-media power, 157, 220-225, 235, 237-241; largeaudience programming, 197, 204-210, 259-260; power of mass media owners, 197, 199-204, 220-225 Fisher, William (Terry), 15, 123, 276, 293, 409 Fiske, John, 135, 275, 293 fixed costs, 110 Folding@home project, 82-83 folk culture. See culture food, commons-based research on, 328-329 food security, commons-based research on, 329-344 formal autonomy theory, 140-141 formal instruction, 314-315 fragmentation of communication, 15, 234-235, 238, 256, 465-466. See also social relations and norms Franklin, Benjamin, 187 Franks, Charles, 81, 137 Free High School Science Texts (FHSST), 101, 326 free software, 5, 46, 63-67; commonsbased welfare development, 320-323; as competition to market-based business, 123; human development and justice, 14; policy on, 436-437; project modularity and granularity, 102; security considerations, 457-458 free trade agreements. See trade policy freedom, 19, 129; behavioral options, 150-152, 170; of commons, 62; cultural, 279-285, 297; property and commons, 143-146 freedom as individuals. See autonomy freedom policy. See policy Freenet, 269-270 Frey, Bruno, 93-94 Friedman, Milton, 38 friendship as motivation. See intrinsic motivations friendships, virtual, 359-361 Friendster, 368 Froomkin, Michael, 412, 432 FTAs. See trade policy future: participatory culture, 297-300; public sphere, 271-272 % ,{[pg 499]}, games, immersive, 74, 135-136 GCP (Generation Challenge Program), 341 GE (General Electric), 191, 195 General Public License (GPL), 63-65, 104. See also free software Generation Challenge Program (GCP), 341 genetically modified (GM) foods, 332-338 Genome@home project, 82 geographic community, strength of. See thickening of preexisting relations Ghosh, Rishab, 106 gifts, 116-117 Gilmore, Dan, 219, 262 Glance, Natalie, 248, 257 global development, 308-311, 355; food and agricultural innovation, 328-344; international harmonization, 453-455; medical and pharmaceutical innovation, 344-353 global injustice. See justice and human development GM (genetically modified) foods, 332-338 GNU/Linux operating system, 64-65 Gnutella, 420 Godelier, Maurice, 109, 116 golden rice, 339 goods, information-embedded, 311-312 Google, 76 Gould, Stephen Jay, 27 government: authoritarian control, 236, 266-271; independence from control of, 184, 197-198; role of, 20-22; working around authorities, 266-271. See also policy GPL (General Public License), 63-65, 104. See also free software Gramsci, Antonio, 280 Granovetter, Mark, 95, 360, 361 granularity, 100-102; of lumpy goods, 113-114 Green Revolution, 331-332 Grokster, 421 growth rates of Web sites, 244, 246-247 gTLD-MoU document, 431 Habermas, Jurgen, 181, 184, 205, 281, 412 The Halloween Memo, 123 Hampton, Keith, 363 handhelds. See computers; mobile phones HapMap Project, 351 hardware, 105; infrastructure ownership, 155; policy on physical devices, 408-412; as shareable, lumpy goods, 113-115 hardware regulations, 408-412 harmonization, international, 453-455 Harris, Bev, 227, 228, 231 Hart, Michael, 80-81, 137 Hayek, Friedrich, 20, 143 HDI (Human Development Index), 309-310 health effects of GM foods, 334 Hearst, William Randolph, 203 Heller, Michael, 312 HHI (Herfindahl-Hirschman Index), 202 hierarchical organizations. See traditional model of communication high-production value content, 167-169, 294-297. See also accreditation HIV/AIDS, 319, 328-329, 344-345; Genome home project, 82 Holiday, Billie, 273 Hollings, Fritz, 409-410 Hollywood. See entertainment industry Hoover, Herbert, 192-194 Hopkins Report, 229 Horner, Mark, 101 Huberman, Bernardo, 243-244, 246-247 human affairs, technology and, 16-18 % ,{[pg 500]}, human communicative capacity, 52-55; feasibility conditions for social production, 99-106; pricing, 110 human community, coexisting with Internet, 375-377 human contact, online vs. physical, 360-361 human development and justice, 13-15, 301-355, 467-468; commons-based research, 317-328; commons-based strategies, 308-311; liberal theories of, 303-308. See also welfare Human Development Index (HDI), 309-310 Human Development Report, 309 human freedom. See freedom human motivation, 6, 92-99; crowding out theory, 115; cultural context of, 97; granularity of participation and, 100-102, 113-114 human welfare, 130-131; commons-based research, 317-328; commons-based strategies, 308-311; digital divide, 236-237; freedom from constraint, 157-158; information-based advantages, 311-315; liberal theories of justice, 303-308. See also justice and human development Hundt, Reed, 222 hyperlinking on the Web, 218; power law distribution of site connections, 241-261; as trespass, 451-453 IAHC (International Ad Hoc Committee), 430-431 IANA (Internet Assigned Numbers Authority), 430 IBM's business strategy, 46-47, 123-124 ICANN (Internet Corporation for Assigned Names and Numbers), 431-432 iconic representations of opinion, 205, 209-210 ideal market, 62-63 immersive entertainment, 74, 135-136 implicit knowledge, transfer of, 314-315 incentives of exclusive rights. See proprietary rights incentives to produce, 6, 92-99; crowding out theory, 115; cultural context of, 97; granularity of participation and, 100-102, 113-114 independence from government control, 184, 197-198 independence of Web sites, 103 individual autonomy, 8-9, 133-175, 464-465; culture and, 280-281; formal conception of, 140-141; independence of Web sites, 103; individual capabilities in, 20-22; information environment, structure of, 146-161; mass media and, 164-166 individual capabilities and action, 20-22; coordinated effects of individual actions, 4-5; cultural shift, 284; economic condition and, 304; human capacity as resource, 52-55; as modality of production, 119-120; as physical capital, 99; technology and human affairs, 16-18. See also autonomy; nonmarket information producers individualist methodologies, 18 industrial age: destabilization of, 32; reduction of individual autonomy, 137-138 industrial model of communication, 4, 9, 22-28, 59-60, 383-459, 470-471; autonomy and, 164-166; barriers to justice, 302; emerging role of mass media, 178-180, 185-186, 198-199; enclosure movement, 380-382; information industries, 315-317; mapping, framework for, 389-396; medical innovation and, 345-346; path dependency, 386-389; relationship with social producers, 122-127; securityrelated policy, 73-74, 396, 457-459; shift away from, 10-13; stakes of information policy, 460-473; structure of mass media, 178-180; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116. See also marketbased information producers % ,{[pg 501]}, inefficiency of information regulation, 36-41, 49-50, 106-116, 461-462; capacity reallocation, 114-116; property protections, 319; wireless communications policy, 154 inertness, political, 197, 204-210 influence exaction, 156, 158-159 information, defined, 31, 313-314 information, perfect, 203 information appropriation strategies, 49 information as nonrival, 36-39 information economy, 2-34; democracy and liberalism, 7-16; effects on public sphere, 219-233; emergence of, 2-7; institutional ecology, 22-28; justice, liberal theories of, 303-308; methodological choices, 16-22 information-embedded goods, 311-312 information-embedded tools, 312 information flow, 12; controlling with policy routers, 147-149, 156, 197-198, 397; large-audience programming, 197, 204-210, 259-260; limited by mass media, 197-199 information industries, 315-317 information laws. See policy information licensing and ownership. See also proprietary rights information overload and Babel objection, 10, 12, 169-174, 233-235, 237-241, 465-466 information production, 464; feasibility conditions for social production, 99-106; networked public sphere capacity for, 225-232; nonrivalry, 36-39, 85-86; physical constraints on, 3-4; strategies of, 41-48. See also distribution of information; peer production information production, market-based: cultural change, transparency of, 290-293; mass popular culture, 295-296; relationship with social producers, 122-127; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116; universities as, 347-348; without property protections, 39-41, 45-48 information production, models of. See traditional model of communication information production, nonmarketbased. See entries at nonmarket production information production capital, 6-7, 32; control of, 99; cost minimization and benefit maximization, 42; fixed and initial costs, 110; production costs as limiting, 164-165; transaction costs, 59-60. See also commons; social capital information production economics, 35-58; current production strategies, 41-48; exclusive rights, 49-50, 56-58; production over computer networks, 50-56 information production efficiency. See efficiency of information regulation information production inputs, 68-75; existing information, 37-39, 52; immersive entertainment, 74-75; individual action as modality, 119-120; large-audience programming, 197, 204-210, 259-260; limited by mass media, 197-199; NASA Clickworkers project, 69-70; pricing, 109-113; propaganda, 149-150, 220-225, 297-300; systematically blocked by policy routers, 147-149, 156, 197-198, 397; universal intake, 182, 197-199; Wikipedia project, 70-74. See also collaborative authorship information sharing. See sharing information storage capacity, 86; transaction costs, 112-115 infrastructure ownership, 155 initial costs, 110 % ,{[pg 502]}, injustice. See justice and human development Innis, Harold, 17 innovation: agricultural, commonsbased, 329-344; human development, 14; software patents and, 437-439; wireless communications policy, 154 innovation economics, 35-58; current production strategies, 41-48; exclusive rights, 49-50, 56-58; production over computer networks, 50-56 innovation efficiency. See efficiency of information regulation inputs to production, 68-75; existing information, 37-39, 52; immersive entertainment, 74-75; individual action as modality, 119-120; large-audience programming, 197, 204-210, 259-260; limited by mass media, 197-199; NASA Clickworkers project, 69-70; pricing, 109-113; propaganda, 149-150, 220-225, 297-300; systematically blocked by policy routers, 147-149, 156, 197-198, 397; universal intake, 182, 197-199; Wikipedia project, 70-74. See also collaborative authorship instant messaging, 365 Institute for One World Health, 350 institutional ecology of digital environment, 4, 9, 22-28, 59-60, 383-459, 470-471; autonomy and, 164-166; barriers to justice, 302; emerging role of mass media, 178-180, 185-186, 198-199; enclosure movement, 380-382; mapping, framework for, 389-396; medical innovation and, 345-346; path dependency, 386-389; relationship with social producers, 122-127; security-related policy, 73-74, 396, 457-459; shift away from, 10-13; stakes of information policy, 460-473; structure of mass media, 178-180; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116. See also market-based information producers intellectual property. See proprietary rights interaction, social. See social relations and norms interest communities. See clusters in network topology interlinking. See topology, network International HapMap Project, 351 international harmonization, 453-455 Internet: authoritarian control over, 266-271; centralization of, 235, 237-241; coexisting with human community, 375-377; democratizing effect of, 213-214, 233-237; globality of, effects on policy, 396; linking as trespass, 451-453; plasticity of culture, 294-297, 299; as platform for human connection, 369-372; power law distribution of site connections, 241-261; strongly connected Web sites, 249-250; technologies of, 215-219; transparency of culture, 285-294; Web addresses, 429-434; Web browsers, 434-436 Internet Explorer browser, 434-436 Internet usage patterns. See social relations and norms intrinsic motivations, 94-99. See also motivation to produce Introna, Lucas, 261 isolation, 359-361 Jackson, Jesse, 264 The Jedi Saga, 134 Jefferson, Richard, 342 Joe Einstein model, 43, 47-48, 315 Johanson, Jon, 417 journalism, undermined by commercialism, 197, 204-210 judgment of relevance. See relevance filtering justice and human development, 13-15, 301-355, 467-468; commons-based research, 317-328; commons-based strategies, 308-311; liberal theories of, 303-308 % ,{[pg 503]}, Kant, Immanuel, 143 karma (Slashdot), 78 KaZaa, 421 KDKA Pittsburgh, 190, 191 Keillor, Garrison, 243 Kick, Russ, 103, 259-260 Know-How model, 45-46 knowledge, defined, 314-315 Koren, Niva Elkin, 15 Kottke, Jason, 252 Kraut, Robert, 360, 363 Kumar, Ravi, 253 Kymlicka, Will, 281 laboratories, peer-produced, 352-353 Lakhani, Karim, 106 Lange, David, 25 large-audience programming, 197, 204-210; susceptibility of networked public sphere, 259-260 large-circulation presses, 187-188 large-grained goods, 113-114 large-scale peer cooperation. See peer production last mile (wireless), 402-405 laws. See policy layers of institutional ecology, 384, 389-396, 469-470; content layer, 384, 392, 395, 439-457, 469-470; physical layer, 392, 469-470. See also logical layer of institutional ecology learning networks, 43, 46, 112 Lemley, Mark, 399, 445 Lerner, Josh, 39, 106 Lessig, Lawrence (Larry), 15, 25, 239, 276, 278, 385, 399 liberal political theory, 19-20; cultural freedom, 278-285, 297 liberal societies, 7-16; autonomy, 8-9; critical culture and social relations, 15-16; design of public sphere, 180-185; justice and human development, 13-15; public sphere, shift from mass media, 10-13; theories of justice, 303-308 licensing: agricultural biotechnologies, 338-344; GPL (General Public License), 63-65, 104; radio, 191-194; shrink-wrap (contractual enclosure), 444-446. See also proprietary rights limited-access common resources, 61 limited intake of mass media, 197-199 limited sharing networks, 43, 48 Lin, Nan, 95 Linden Labs. See Second Life game environment linking on the Web, 218; power law distribution of site connections, 241-261; as trespass, 451-453 Linux operating system, 65-66 Litman, Jessica, 25, 33, 278, 439 local clusters in network topology, 12-13. See also clusters in network topology logical layer of institutional ecology, 384, 392, 412-439, 469; database protection, 449-451; DMCA (Digital Millennium Copyright Act), 380, 413-418; domain name system, 429-434; free software policies, 436-437; international harmonization, 453-455; peerto-peer networks, 83-86, 418-428, 457; recent changes, 395; trademark dilution, 290, 446-448; Web browsers, 434-436 loneliness, 359-361 loose affiliations, 9, 357, 362, 366-369 Los Alamos model, 43, 48 Lott, Trent, 258, 263-264 lowest-common-denominator programming, 197, 204-210, 259-260 Lucas, George, 134 luck, justice and, 303-304 lumpy goods, 113-115 Luther, Martin, 27 % ,{[pg 504]}, machinery. See computers mailing lists (electronic), 215 management, changing relationships of, 124-126 Mangabeira Unger, Roberto, 138 manipulating perceptions of others, 147-152, 170; influence exaction, 156, 158-159; with propaganda, 149-150, 220-225, 297-300 mapping utterances. See relevance filtering Marconi, 191 market-based information producers: cultural change, transparency of, 290-293; mass popular culture, 295-296; relationship with social producers, 122-127; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116; universities as, 347-348; without property protections, 39-41, 45-48 market reports, access to, 314 market transactions, 107-109 Marshall, Josh, 221, 222, 246, 263 Marx, Karl, 143, 279 mass media: basic critiques of, 196-211; corrective effects of network environment, 220-225; as platform for public sphere, 178-180, 185-186, 198-199; structure of, 178-180. See also traditional model of communication mass media, political freedom and, 176-211; commercial platform for public sphere, 178-180, 185-186, 198-199; criticisms, 196-211; design characteristics of liberal public sphere, 180-185 massive multiplayer games, 74, 135-136 maximizing viewers as business necessity. See large-audience programming McChesney, Robert, 196 McHenry, Robert, 71 McLuhan, Marshall, 16, 17 McVeigh, Timothy (sailor), 367 Medecins San Frontieres, 347 media concentration, 157, 235, 237-241; corrective effects of network environment, 220-225. See also power of mass media owners medicines, commons-based research on, 344-353 medium-grained goods, 113 medium of exchange, 109-113 Meetup.com site, 368 The Memory Hole, 103 metamoderation (Slashdot), 79 methodological individualism, 18 Mickey model, 42-44 Microsoft Corporation: browser wars, 434-436; sidewalk.com, 452 Milgram, Stanley, 252 misfortune, justice and, 303-304 MIT's Open Courseware Initiative, 314-315, 327 MMOGs (massive multiplayer online games), 74, 135-136 mobile phones, 219, 367; open wireless networks, 402-405 moderation of content. See accreditation modularity, 100-103 Moglen, Eben, 5, 55, 426 monetary constraints on information production, 6-7, 32; control of, 99; cost minimization and benefit maximization, 42; fixed and initial costs, 110; production costs as limiting, 164-165; transaction costs, 59-60. See also commons; social capital money: centralization of communications, 258-260; cost minimization and benefit maximization, 42; cost of production as limiting, 164-165; crispness of currency exchange, 109-113; as demotivator, 94-96; as dominant factor, 234. See also capital for production monitoring, authoritarian, 236 monopoly: authoritarian control, 266-271; breadth of programming under, 207; medical research and innovation, 345-346; radio broadcasting, 189, 195; wired environment as, 152-153 % ,{[pg 505]}, Moore, Michael, 200 motivation to produce, 6, 92-99; crowding out theory, 115; cultural context of, 97; granularity of participation and, 100-102, 113-114 Moulitsas, Markos, 221 movie industry. See entertainment industry MP3.com, 419, 422-423 MSF (Medecins San Frontieres), 347 Mumford, Lewis, 16 municipal broadband initiatives, 405-408 Murdoch, Rupert, 203 music industry, 50-51, 425-427; digital sampling, 443-444; DMCA violations, 416; peer-to-peer networks and, 84 MyDD.com site, 221 Napster, 419. See also peer-to-peer networks NASA Clickworkers, 69-70 NBC (National Broadcasting Company), 195 Negroponte, Nicholas, 238 neighborhood relations, strengthening of, 357, 362-366 Nelson, W. R., 205 Netanel, Neil, 236, 261, 261-262 Netscape and browser wars, 435 network topology, 172-173; autonomy and, 146-161; emergent ordered structure, 253-256; linking as trespass, 451-453; moderately linked sites, 251-252; peer-to-peer networks, 83-86, 418-428, 457; power law distribution of site connections, 241-261; quoting on Web, 218; repeater networks, 88-89; strongly connected Web sites, 249-250. See also clusters in network topology networked environment policy. See policy networked information economy, 2-34; democracy and liberalism, 7-16; effects on public sphere, 219-233; emergence of, 2-7; institutional ecology, 22-28; justice, liberal theories of, 303-308; methodological choices, 16-22 networked public sphere, 10-12, 212-271, 465; authoritarian control, working around, 266-271; basic communication tools, 215-219; critiques that Internet democratizes, 233-237; defined, 177-178; Diebold Election Systems case study, 225-232, 262, 389-390; future of, 271-272; Internet as concentrated vs. chaotic, 237-241; liberal, design characteristics of, 180-185; loose affiliations, 9, 357, 362, 366-369; mass-media platform for, 178-180, 185-186, 198-199; topology and connectivity of, 241-261; transparency of Internet culture, 285-294; watchdog functionality, 236, 261-266. See also social relations and norms networked society, 376 news (as data), 314 newspapers, 40, 186-188; market concentration, 202 Newton, Isaac, 37 niche markets, 56 NIH (National Institutes of Health), 324 Nissenbaum, Helen, 261 No Electronic Theft (NET) Act, 441-442 Noam, Eli, 201-202, 238-239 nonexclusion-market production strategies, 39-41, 45-48 nonmarket information producers, 4-5, 39-40; conditions for production, 99-106; cultural change, transparency of, 290-293; emergence of social production, 116-122; relationship with nonmarket information producers (cont.) market-based businesses, 122-127; role of, 18-19; strategies for information production, 43, 47-48; universities as, 347-348 % ,{[pg 506]}, nonmarket production, economics of, 91-127; emergence in digital networks, 116-122; feasibility conditions, 99-106; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116. See also motivation to produce nonmarket strategies, effectiveness of, 54-56 nonmonetary motivations. See motivation to produce nonprofit medical research, 350 nonrival goods, 36-39; peer-to-peer networks sharing, 85-86 norms (social), 72-74, 356-377; enforced norms with software, 372-375; fragmentation of communication, 15, 234-235, 238, 256, 465-466; Internet and human coexistence, 375-377; Internet as platform for, 369-372; loose affiliations, 9, 357, 362, 366-369; motivation within, 92-94; property, commons, and autonomy, 143-146; Slashdot mechanisms for, 78; software for, emergence of, 372-375; technology-defined structure, 29-34; thickening of preexisting relations, 357; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116; working with social expectations, 366-369 Nozick, Robert, 304 NSI (Network Solutions, Inc.), 430 number of behavioral options, 150-152, 170 OAIster protocol, 326 obscurity of some Web sites, 246, 251-252 ODP (Open Directory Project), 76 older Web sites, obscurity of, 246 "on the shoulders of giants", 37-39 One World Health, 350 Open Archives Initiative, 326 open commons, 61 Open Courseware Initiative (MIT), 314-315, 327 Open Directory Project (ODP), 76 open-source software, 5, 46, 63-67; commons-based welfare development, 320-323; as competition to marketbased business, 123; human development and justice, 14; policy on, 436-437; project modularity and granularity, 102; security considerations, 457-458 open wireless networks, 402-405; municipal broadband initiatives, 405-408; security, 457 opinion, public: iconic representations of, 205, 209-210; synthesis of, 184, 199. See also accreditation; relevance filtering opportunities created by social production, 123-126 options, behavioral, 150-152, 170 order, emergent. See clusters in network topology organization structure, 100-106; granularity, 100-102, 113-114; justice and, 303-304; modularity, 100-103 organizational clustering, 248-249 organizations as persons, 19-20 organized production, traditional. See traditional model of communication OSTG (Open Source Technology Group), 77 Ostrom, Elinor, 144 owners of mass media, power of, 197, 199-204; corrective effects of network environment, 220-225 ownership of information. See also proprietary rights p2p networks, 83-86, 418-428; security considerations, 457 % ,{[pg 507]}, packet filtering. See blocked access Pantic, Drazen, 219 Pareto, Vilfredo, 243 participatory culture, 297-300. See also culture passive vs. active consumers, 126-127, 135 patents. See proprietary rights path dependency, 388-389 patterns of Internet use. See social relations and norms peer production, 5, 33, 59-90, 462-464; drug research and development, 351; electronic voting machines (case study), 225-232; feasibility conditions for social production, 99-106; loose affiliations, 9, 357, 362, 366-369; maintenance of cooperation, 104; as platform for human connection, 374-375; relationship with market-based businesses, 122-127; sustainability of, 106-116; watchdog functionality, 236, 261-266. See also sharing peer production, order emerging from. See accreditation; relevance filtering peer review of scientific publications, 323-325 peer-to-peer networks, 83-86, 418-428; security considerations, 457 Pennock, David, 251 perceptions of others, shaping, 147-152, 170; influence exaction, 156, 158-159; with propaganda, 149-150, 220-225, 297-300 perfect information, 203 performance as means of communication, 205 permission to communicate, 155 permissions. See proprietary rights personal computers, 105; infrastructure ownership, 155; policy on physical devices, 408-412; as shareable, lumpy goods, 113-115 Pew studies, 364-365, 423 pharmaceuticals, commons-based research on, 344-353 Philadelphia, wireless initiatives in, 406-408 physical capital for production, 6-7, 32, 384, 396-412; control of, 99; cost minimization and benefit maximization, 42; fixed and initial costs, 110; production costs as limiting, 164-165; transaction costs, 59-60. See also commons; social capital physical constraints on information production, 3-4, 24-25. See also capital for production physical contact, diminishment of, 360-361 physical layer of institutional ecology, 392, 469-470; recent changes, 395 physical machinery and computers, 105; infrastructure ownership, 155; policy on physical devices, 408-412; as shareable, lumpy goods, 113-115 Piore, Michael, 138 PIPRA (Public Intellectual Property for Agriculture), 338-341 planned modularization, 101-102 plasticity of Internet culture, 294-297, 299 PLoS (Public Library of Science), 324 polarization, 235, 256-258 policy, 26, 383-459; authoritarian control, 266-271; commons-based research, 317-328; Diebold Election Systems case study, 225-232, 262, 389-390; enclosure movement, 380-382; global Internet and, 396; independence from government control, 184, 197-198; international harmonization, 453-455; liberal theories of justice, 305-307; mapping institutional ecology, 389-396; participatory culture, 297-300; path dependency, 386-389; pharmaceutical innovation, 345-346; property-based, 159-160; proprietary policy (continued ) rights vs. justice, 302-303; securityrelated, 73-74, 396, 457-459; stakes of, 460-473; wireless spectrum rights, 87. See also privatization; proprietary rights % ,{[pg 508]}, policy, global. See global development policy, social. See social relations and norms policy efficiency. See efficiency of information regulation policy layers, 384, 389-396, 469-470; content layer, 384, 392, 395, 439-457, 469-470; physical layer, 392, 469-470. See also logical layer of institutional ecology policy routers, 147-149, 156, 197-198, 397; influence exaction, 156, 158-159 political concern, undermined by commercialism, 197, 204-210 political freedom, mass media and, 176-211; commercial platform for public sphere, 178-180, 185-186, 198-199; criticisms, 196-211; design characteristics of liberal public sphere, 180-185 political freedom, public sphere and, 212-271; authoritarian control, working around, 266-271; basic communication tools, 215-219; critiques that Internet democratizes, 233-237; future of, 271-272; Internet as concentrated vs. chaotic, 237-241; topology and connectivity of, 241-261; watchdog functionality, 236, 261-266. See also networked information economy politics. See policy Pool, Ithiel de Sola, 388 popular culture, commercial production of, 295-296 Post, Robert, 140 Postel, Jon, 430 Postman, Neil, 186 poverty. See justice and human development; welfare Powell, Walter, 112 power law distribution of Web connections, 241-261; strongly connected Web sites, 249-250; uniform component of moderate connectivity, 251-252 power of mass media owners, 197, 199-204; corrective effects of network environment, 220-225 preexisting relations, thickening of, 357 press, commercial, 186-188, 202 price compensation, as demotivator, 94-96 pricing, 109-113 Pringle, Peter, 335 print media, commercial, 186-188 private communications, 177 privatization: agricultural biotechnologies, 335-336; of communications and information systems, 152-154, 159-160 /{ProCD v. Zeidenberg}/, 445 processing capacity, 81-82, 86 processors. See computers producer surplus, 157 production capital, 6-7, 32; control of, 99; cost minimization and benefit maximization, 42; fixed and initial costs, 110; production costs as limiting, 164-165; transaction costs, 59-60. See also commons; social capital production inputs, 68-75; existing information, 37-39, 52; immersive entertainment, 74-75; individual action as modality, 119-120; large-audience programming, 197, 204-210, 259-260; limited by mass media, 197-199; NASA Clickworkers project, 69-70; pricing, 109-113; propaganda, 149-150, 220-225, 297-300; systematically blocked by policy routers, 147-149, 156, 197-198, 397; universal intake, 182, 197-199; Wikipedia project, 70-74. See also collaborative authorship % ,{[pg 509]}, production of information, 464; feasibility conditions for social production, 99-106; networked public sphere capacity for, 225-232; nonrivalry, 36-39, 85-86; physical constraints on, 3-4; strategies of, 41-48. See also distribution of information; peer production production of information, efficiency of. See efficiency of information regulation production of information, industrial model of. See traditional model of communication production of information, nonmarket. See nonmarket information producers professionalism, mass media, 198 Project Gutenberg, 80-81, 136 propaganda, 149-150; manipulating culture, 297-300; Stolen Honor documentary, 220-225 property ownership, 23-27, 129-132; autonomy and, 143-146; control over, as asymmetric, 60-61; effects of exclusive rights, 49-50; trade policy, 319. See also commons; proprietary rights property ownership, efficiency of. See efficiency of information regulation proprietary rights, 22-28, 56-58; agricultural biotechnologies, 335-336, 338-344; commons-based research, 317-328; contractual enclosure, 444-446; copyright issues, 439-444; cultural environment and, 277-278; database protection, 449-451; Digital Millennium Copyright Act (DMCA), 380, 413-418; domain names, 431-433; dominance of, overstated, 460-461; effects of, 49-50; enclosure movement, 380-382; global welfare and research, 317-320, 354-355; information-embedded goods and tools, 311-312; infrastructure ownership, 155; international harmonization, 453-455; justice vs., 302-303; medical and pharmaceutical innovation, 345-346; models of, 42-45; openness of personal computers, 409; peer-to-peer networks and, 84-85; radio patents, 191, 194; scientific publication, 323-325; software patenting, 437-439; strategies for information production, 41-48; trademark dilution, 290, 446-448; trespass to chattels, 451-453; university alliances, 338-341; wireless networks, 87, 153-154. See also access proprietary rights, inefficiency of, 36-41, 49-50, 106-116, 461-462; capacity reallocation, 114-116; property protections, 319; wireless communications policy, 154 psychological motivation. See motivation to produce public-domain data, 313-314 public goods vs. nonrival goods, 36-39 Public Library of Science (PLoS), 324 public opinion: iconic representations of, 205, 209-210; synthesis of, 184, 199. See also accreditation; relevance filtering public sphere, 10-12, 212-271, 465; authoritarian control, working around, 266-271; basic communication tools, 215-219; critiques that Internet democratizes, 233-237; defined, 177-178; Diebold Election Systems case study, 225-232, 262, 389-390; future of, 271-272; Internet as concentrated vs. chaotic, 237-241; liberal, design characteristics of, 180-185; loose affiliations, 9, 357, 362, 366-369; massmedia platform for, 178-180, 185-186, 198-199; topology and connectivity of, 241-261; transparency of Internet culture, 285-294; watchdog functionality, 236, 261-266 public sphere economy. See networked information economy % ,{[pg 510]}, public sphere relationships. See social relations and norms publication, scientific, 313, 323-328 Putnam, Robert, 362 quality of information. See accreditation; high-production value content; relevance filtering quoting on Web, 218 radio, 186-196, 387-388, 402-403; market concentration, 202; patents, 191, 194; as platform for human connection, 369; as public sphere platform, 190. See also wireless communications Radio Act of 1927, 196 Radio B92, 266 radio telephony, 194 raw data, 313-314; database protection, 449-451 raw materials of information. See inputs to production Rawls, John, 184, 279, 303-304, 306 Raymond, Eric, 66, 137, 259 Raz, Joseph, 140 RCA (Radio Corporation of America), 191, 195 RCA strategy, 43, 44 reallocating excess capacity, 81-89, 114-115, 157, 351-352 recognition. See intrinsic motivations redistribution theory, 304 referencing on the Web, 218; linking as trespass, 451-453; power law distribution of Web site connections, 241-261 regional clusters in network topology, 12-13. See also clusters in network topology regions of interest. See clusters in network topology regulated commons, 61 regulating information, efficiency of, 36-41, 49-50, 106-116, 461-462; capacity reallocation, 114-116; property protections, 319; wireless communications policy, 154 regulation. See policy regulation by social norms, 72-74, 356-377; enforced norms with software, 372-375; fragmentation of communication, 15, 234-235, 238, 256, 465-466; Internet and human coexistence, 375-377; Internet as platform for, 369-372; loose affiliations, 9, 357, 362, 366-369; motivation within, 92-94; property, commons, and autonomy, 143-146; Slashdot mechanisms for, 78; software for, emergence of, 372-375; technology-defined structure, 29-34; thickening of preexisting relations, 357; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116; working with social expectations, 366-369 Reichman, Jerome, 449 relationships, social. See social relations and norms relevance filtering, 68, 75-80, 169-174, 183, 258-260; Amazon, 75; by authoritarian countries, 236; capacity for, by mass media, 199; concentration of mass-media power, 157, 220-225, 235, 237-241; as distributed system, 171-172; Google, 76; Open Directory Project (ODP), 76; power of mass media owners, 197, 199-204, 220-225; as public good, 12; Slashdot, 76-80, 104; watchdog functionality, 236, 261-266 relevance filtering by information providers. See blocked access repeater networks, 88-89 research, commons-based, 317-328, 354-355; food and agricultural innovation, 328-344; medical and pharmaceutical innovation, 344-353 resource sharing. See capacity, sharing % ,{[pg 511]}, resources, common. See commons responsive communications, 199 reuse of information, 37-39, 52 reward. See motivation to produce Reynolds, Glenn, 264 Rheingold, Howard, 219, 265, 358-359 RIAA (Recording Industry Association of America), 416 right to read, 439-440 rights. See proprietary rights Romantic Maximizer model, 42-43 Rose, Carol, 61 routers, controlling information flow with, 147-149, 156, 197-198, 397; influence exaction, 156, 158-159 Rubin, Aviel, 228, 229 Sabel, Charles, 62, 111, 138 Saltzer, Jerome, 399 sampling, digital (music), 443-444 Samuelson, Pamela, 25, 414, 488 Sarnoff, David, 195 SBG (Sinclair Broadcast Group), 199-200, 220-225 Scholarly Lawyers model, 43, 45 scientific data, access to, 313-314 scientific publication, 313; commons-based welfare development, 323-328 scope of loose relationships, 9, 357 Scott, William, 353 Second Life game environment, 74-75, 136 security of context, 143-146 security-related policy, 396, 457-459; vandalism on Wikipedia, 73-74 Security Systems Standards and Certification Act, 409 self-archiving of scientific publications, 325-326 self-determinism, extrinsic motivation and, 94 self-direction. See autonomy self-esteem, extrinsic motivation and, 94 self-organization. See clusters in network topology self-reflection, 15-16, 293-294; Open Directory Project, 76; selfidentification as transaction cost, 112; Wikipedia project, 70-74 services, software, 322-323 SETI@home project, 81-83 shaping perceptions of others, 147-152, 170; influence exaction, 156, 158-159; with propaganda, 149-150, 220-225, 297-300 Shapiro, Carl, 312 shareable goods, 113-115 sharing, 59-90, 81-89; emergence of social production, 116-122; excess capacity, 81-89, 114-115, 157, 351-352; limited sharing networks, 43, 48; open wireless networks, 402-405; radio capacity, 402-403; technologydependence of, 120; university patents, 347-350 sharing peer-to-peer. See peer-to-peer networks Shirky, Clay, 173, 252, 368, 373 "shoulders of giants", 37-39 shrink-wrap licenses, 444-446 sidewalk.com, 452 Simon, Herbert, 243 Sinclair Broadcast Group (SBG), 199-200, 220-225 Skype utility, 86, 421 Slashdot, 76-80, 104 small-worlds effect, 252-253 SMS (short message service). See text messaging social action, 22 social capital, 95-96, 361-369; networked society, 366-369; thickening of preexisting relations, 363-366 social clustering, 248-249 % ,{[pg 512]}, social-democratic theories of justice, 308-311 social motivation. See intrinsic motivations social production, relationship with market-based businesses, 122-127 social relations and norms, 72-74, 356-377; enforced norms with software, 372-375; fragmentation of communication, 15, 234-235, 238, 256, 465-466; Internet and human coexistence, 375-377; Internet as platform for, 369-372; loose affiliations, 9, 357, 362, 366-369; motivation within, 92-94; property, commons, and autonomy, 143-146; Slashdot mechanisms for, 78; software for, emergence of, 372-375; technology-defined structure, 29-34; thickening of preexisting relations, 357; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116; working with social expectations, 366-369 social software, 372-375 social structure, defined by technology, 29-34 societal culture. See culture software: commons-based welfare development, 320-323; patents for, 437-439; social, 372-375 software, open-source, 5, 46, 63-67; commons-based welfare development, 320-323; as competition to marketbased business, 123; human development and justice, 14; policy on, 436-437; project modularity and granularity, 102; security considerations, 457-458 Solum, Lawrence, 267 Sonny Bono Copyright Term Extension Act of 1998, 442-443, 454 specificity of price, 109-113 spectrum property rights, 87. See also proprietary rights spiders. See trespass to chattels Spielberg, Steven, 416 stakes of information policy, 460-473 Stallman, Richard, 5, 64-66 standardizing creativity, 109-113 Starr, Paul, 17, 388 state, role of, 20-22 static inefficiency. See efficiency of information regulation static Web pages, 216 Steiner, Peter, 205 Stolen Honor documentary, 220-225 storage capacity, 86; transaction costs, 112-115 strategies for information production, 41-48; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116 Strogatz, Steven, 252 strongly connected Web sites, 249-250 structure of mass media, 178-180 structure of network, 172-173; autonomy and, 146-161; emergent ordered structure, 253-256; linking as trespass, 451-453; moderately linked sites, 251-252; peer-to-peer networks, 83-86, 418-428, 457; power law distribution of Web site connections, 241-261; quoting on Web, 218; repeater networks, 88-89; strongly connected Web sites, 249-250. See also clusters in network topology structure of networks. See network topology structure of organizations, 100-106; granularity, 100-102, 113-114; justice and, 303-304; modularity, 100-103 structured production, 100-106; granularity, 100-102, 113-114; maintenance of cooperation, 104; modularity, 100-103 Sunstein, Cass, 234 supercomputers, 81-82 supplantation of real-world interaction, 357, 362-366 % ,{[pg 513]}, supply-side effects of information production, 45-46 sustainability of peer production, 106-116 symmetric commons, 61-62 Syngenta, 337 synthesis of public opinion, 184, 199. See also accreditation TalkingPoints site, 221 taste, changes in, 126 Taylor, Fredrick, 138 teaching materials, 326 technology, 215-219; agricultural, 335-344; costs of, 462; dependence on, for sharing, 120; effectiveness of nonmarket strategies, 54-55; enabling social sharing as production modality, 120-122; role of, 16-18; social software, 372-375; social structure defined by, 29-34 telephone, as platform for human connection, 371 television, 186; culture of, 135; Internet use vs., 360, 364; large-audience programming, 197, 204-210, 259-260; market concentration, 202 tendrils (Web topology), 249-250 term of copyright, 442-443, 454 text distribution as platform for human connection, 369 text messaging, 219, 365, 367 textbooks, 326 thickening of preexisting relations, 357, 362-366 thinness of online relations, 360 Thurmond, Strom, 263 Ticketmaster, 452 Tirole, Jean, 94, 106 Titmuss, Richard, 93 de Tocqueville, Alexis, 187 toll broadcasting, 194-195 too much information. See Babel objection; relevance filtering tools, information-embedded, 312 Toomey, Jenny, 123 topical clustering, 248-249 topology, network, 172-173; autonomy and, 146-161; emergent ordered structure, 253-256; linking as trespass, 451-453; moderately linked sites, 251-252; peer-to-peer networks, 83-86, 418-428, 457; power law distribution of Web site connections, 241-261; quoting on Web, 218; repeater networks, 88-89; strongly connected Web sites, 249-250. See also clusters in network topology Torvalds, Linus, 65-66, 104-105, 136-137 trade policy, 317-320, 354-355, 454 trademark dilution, 290, 446-448. See also proprietary rights traditional model of communication, 4, 9, 22-28, 59-60, 383-459, 470-471; autonomy and, 164-166; barriers to justice, 302; emerging role of mass media, 178-180, 185-186, 198-199; enclosure movement, 380-382; mapping, framework for, 389-396; medical innovation and, 345-346; path dependency, 386-389; relationship with social producers, 122-127; security-related policy, 73-74, 396, 457-459; shift away from, 10-13; stakes of information policy, 460-473; structure of mass media, 178-180; transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116. See also market-based information producers transaction costs, 59-60, 106-116 transfer of knowledge, 314-315 transparency of free software, 322 transparency of Internet culture, 285-294 transport channel policy, 397-408; broadband regulation, 399-402; municipal broadband initiatives, 405-408; open wireless networks, 402-405 trespass to chattels, 451-453 troll filters (Slashdot), 78 trusted systems, computers as, 409-410 tubes (Web topology), 249-250 UCC (Uniform Commercial Code), 445 UCITA (Uniform Computer Information Transactions Act), 444-446 Uhlir, Paul, 449 universal intake, 182, 197-199 university alliances, 338-341, 347-350 university-owned radio, 192 unregulated commons, 61 use permissions. See proprietary rights users as consumers, 126-127 uttering content. See inputs to production vacuity of online relations, 360 Vaidhyanathan, Siva, 278, 488 value-added distribution. See distribution of information; relevance filtering value of online contact, 360 vandalism on Wikipedia, 73-74 variety of behavioral options, 150-152, 170 Varmus, Harold, 313 virtual communities, 348-361. See also social relations and norms visibility of mass media, 198 volunteer activity. See nonmarket information producers; peer production volunteer computation resources. See capacity, sharing von Hippel, Eric, 5, 47, 106, 127 voting, electronic, 225-232, 262, 389-390 vouching for others, network of, 368 Waltzer, Michael, 281 % ,{[pg 514]}, watchdog functionality, 236, 261-266 Watts, Duncan, 252 weak ties of online relations, 360, 363 Web, 216, 218; backbone sites, 249-250, 258-260; browser wars, 434-436; domain name addresses, 429-434; linking as trespass, 451-453; power law distribution of Web site connections, 241-261; quoting from other sites, 218. See also Internet Web topology. See network topology Weber, Steve, 104-105 welfare, 130-131; commons-based research, 317-328; commons-based strategies, 308-311; digital divide, 236-237; freedom from constraint, 157-158; information-based advantages, 311-315; liberal theories of justice, 303-308. See also justice and human development well-being, 19 WELL (Whole Earth `Lectronic Link), 358 Wellman, Barry, 16, 17, 362, 363, 366 Westinghouse, 191, 195 wet-lab science, peer production of, 352-353 WiFi. See wireless communications Wikibooks project, 101 Wikipedia project, 70-74, 104; Barbie doll content, 287-289, 292 Wikis as social software, 372-375 Williamson, Oliver, 59 Winner, Langdon, 17 wired communications: market structure of, 152-153; policy on, 399-402. See also broadband networks wireless communications, 87-89; municipal broadband initiatives, 405-408; open networks, 402-405; privatization vs. commons, 152-154. See also radio World Wide Web, 216, 218; backbone sites, 249-250, 258-260; browser wars, 434-436; domain name addresses, 429-434; linking as trespass, 451-453; power law distribution of Web site connections, 241-261; quoting from other sites, 218. See also Internet % ,{[pg 515]}, writable Web, 216-217 written communication as platform for human connection, 369 Zipf, George, 243 Zittrain, Jonathan, 268